Following my previous post, I had a number of
after-thoughts and reflections along the lines that perhaps I had not dealt
with the issue as comprehensively as I might have. In particular, I worried
that some readers might have gained the impression that I was giving precedence
to cultural over economic aspirations of Indigenous land holders. To the
contrary, my view is that both are legitimate aspirations deserving of equal support
from policymakers. This post is an attempt to rectify that omission, again as
far as possible in non-technical language.
But first an update on the Native Title Amendment
(Indigenous Land Use Agreements) Bill. The Senate Legal and Constitutional Affairs
Legislation Committee has now issued its final report: link
here.
As predicted in my previous post, the Committee has recommended the Bill be
passed, with Labor and the Greens critical of the rushed introduction of the
Bill and limited consultation. Labor supports the Bill whereas the Greens
oppose it and issued a minority report setting out their reasons.
Stakeholder responses have been muted and largely positive.
The Minerals Council and related bodies in Queensland and Western Australia
issued a media release welcoming the ‘considered report’: link
here.
An Aboriginal group involved in opposing the Adani Coal mine issued a media
release critical of Labor for supporting the Bill: link
here.
The National Native Title Council, the Indigenous peak body on native title
issues have remained silent, with no media release on their website (they
supported the Bill).
The Government will consider a number of minor adjustments
proposed by the Committee and may make amendments. The Bill will likely pass
the Senate with Labor support and thus amend the Native Title Act once the
House of Representatives reconsiders any Government amendments.
As argued in my previous post (and in my own submission to
the Committee: link
here) I am concerned that the proposals in the Bill open a pathway to the
undermining of communal decisions over land management, and thus to the very
nature of communal title itself.
I turn now to the issues of inalienability and communal
title. The High Court in Mabo acknowledged that native title continues to exist
in Australia as part of our common law, and that the rights involved were not
able to be bought and sold (that is it is inalienable) and were held by all
members of the relevant land owning group according to Indigenous tradition
(that is it is a communal property right).
My previous post made an argument in favour of respecting
the diversity of Indigenous approaches to managing their country, and against
imposing arbitrary decision rules based on western notions of fairness (such as
majority voting) in relation to management of Indigenous land. In particular, I
was concerned that changes to decision rules (such as have been proposed by the
Government in the current Native Title Amendment Bill) might have the effect of
creating a opportunities for undermining the communal nature of native title.
I didn’t make the argument, but given the capacity of
claimant groups to agree to the extinguishment of native title in return for
other benefits, one might argue that a similar opportunity to undermine
inalienability might also be created. Certainly, in the context of the Native
Title Amendment Bill discussed above, the Committee discussed and appeared to
accept that this is a real issue when it stated at paragraph 2.74:
Moreover,
the Commonwealth should examine the proposals to amend the Act, so that where
ILUAs involve particularly significant consequences for native title holders (such
as the surrender of native title rights), then the minority viewpoint is given
due consideration, perhaps through a higher threshold for decision-making.
Unfortunately, this sentiment was not included in the
Committee’s recommendation.
The arguments against communal and inalienable title have a
long history in conservative circles, and essentially boil down to concerns
that they impact adversely on economic incentives, and thus inhibit economic
development; that communal title is akin to socialism, and inhibits individual
enterprise, and that inalienable title is not able to be used to secure debt
finance (as a bank cannot step in and sell the land involved where a borrower
defaults on a loan, and thus will not lend in the first place) and that this
too is an inhibition against economic enterprise and thus economic development.
For those interested in considering and assessing these arguments (amongst
others), a good place to start is with Helen Hughes book Lands of Shame, published by the Centre for Independent Studies in
2007: link
here.
Interestingly, a more progressive analyst, barrister David
Yarrow, has also made an argument against the notion of inalienable native
title from a perspective which highlights the alleged inequality and
disadvantage inherent in the constraint of inalienability; refer to his article
‘The inalienability of native title in Australia’ in Brennan et al ‘Native
title from Mabo to Akiba’ published by the Federation Press in 2015: link
here.
My own view (contra Hughes and Yarrow) is that while there
is logical merit to these arguments, they ignore the issue of respect for
Indigenous cultural values and the core elements of Indigenous land ownership.
Moreover, there is a policy solution based on the use of
long term leases which both protects the core ontological and cosmological
integrity of Indigenous notions of land and ‘’country’ and rebalances the
opportunities for economic development. Properly designed, such mechanisms
protect the underlying title while allowing individual or corporate enterprises
and commercial or residential developments to proceed with security of tenure
and a capacity for lenders to step in and repossess if necessary.
Clearly, under the various statutory land rights models in
place, there needs to be specific provision for such arrangements. The NT land
rights legislation has always had provision for leases (section 19) and since
2006 has had provisions related to so-called ‘township leases’ (section 19A).
The Native Title Act has general agreement related
provisions, but no specific provision for native title holders to issue leases
over determined native title. It is arguable that native title holders with
exclusive possession have the capacity now to issue leases over their land.
Nevertheless, the recent Northern Australian Development White Paper did
include the idea of making provision for leases (or what they refer to as ‘transferable
interests’) on native title tenure as part of its long term policy agenda; link
here: refer to pp 18 to 26..
There are at least four further constraints on the
leasehold policy ‘solution’ as a driver of economic development; but these constraints
also apply, to a greater or lesser extent, to the conservatives’ preferred
model of freehold tenure.
The first is that the design of the lease mechanism is
crucial; in particular, transaction costs can easily outweigh the benefits which
might be expected to flow from a particular lease. The second is that the
existence of other legislative or technical constraints unrelated to tenure can
often inhibit the operation of economic incentives in remote contexts. One
example in the NT is the planning laws which require subdivisions (funded by
developers) to be in place for leases in excess of 12 years. A third constraint
is that there is a clear policy relevant distinction to be drawn between
appropriate rangeland tenure and that necessary within communities or
townships. Communal and inalienable tenures are more compatible with rangeland
tenure options than in townships. And finally, the financial costs to
government to move from current native title tenures to freehold tenures, given
the just terms provisions in the Australian constitution, are enormous.
The bottom line is that economic development in remote
contexts is much more than changing the characteristics of land tenure, and
indeed, the other factors at play (and I haven’t mentioned the tyranny of
distance; or poor transport and communications infrastructure; or ineffective
and patchy government service provision; or demographic factors) are arguably
of much greater significance in constraining economic outcomes than tenure.
In conclusion, there are sound pragmatic and philosophical
reasons for supporting the existence of inalienable and communal forms of Indigenous
tenure. They align with Indigenous cultural traditions and precepts, and in any
case would be enormously expensive to remove.
Nevertheless, Indigenous groups also have economic
aspirations, and communal and inalienable tenures are not optimal in underpinning
these aspirations. Accordingly, policymakers should seek to facilitate
mechanisms which allow Indigenous landowners to freely decide to establish
subsidiary forms of tenure which are long term, potentially tradable, and
involve low transaction costs. These mechanisms should not however pose a
threat to the underlying Indigenous tenure.
And finally, policymakers and others should not fall into the
trap of suggesting that Indigenous tenure is the only constraint to economic development
in the Indigenous policy domain.
No comments:
Post a Comment