On 20
January, the Assistant Minister to the Prime Minister, Alan Tudge, published an
op ed in the Australian (‘Communal Despair Begins with Grog
Abuse’) outlining
the current state of play on the proposed new Welfare Debit Card, the latest
version of income management for a small cohort of the most disadvantaged welfare
recipients across the nation.
The welfare
debit card, named ‘the Healthy Welfare Card’, was proposed by Andrew Forrest in
his review of Indigenous training and employment, Creating Parity, in 2014, and involves 80 percent of
a welfare recipient’s income being loaded onto a debit card which cannot be used to purchase alcohol,
gambling or to access cash.
The Government’s
proposed welfare debit card is not Indigenous specific and will apply to all
welfare recipients within the trial site locations. Nevertheless, the two
locations chosen to date (Kununurra and Ceduna) both involve a majority of
Indigenous welfare recipients. The reality is that income management of welfare
payments emerged from and retains strong roots within the Indigenous policy
domain based in large part on the inability of governments over the past decade
to make inroads on reducing the high levels of personal and community
disadvantage amongst Indigenous citizens in some locations.
Tudge
appears to be pursuing two political objectives. First, to maintain the
momentum in implementing the new income management scheme following the passage
of legislation late last year with Labor Party support authorising three trials
of the welfare debit card for up to ten thousand recipients; and second, to lay
the foundations for broader (perhaps universal) implementation of the debit
card in the Government’s next term.
In this latter
context, the Australian’s Sarah Martin, writing the same day as Tudge’s op ed
appeared (‘National cashless welfare card plan’), and presumably based on
briefing from the Assistant Minister, began her column as follows: “A cashless
welfare card aimed at stemming alcohol abuse would be rolled out across the
country under a welfare reform the Turnbull Government is considering taking to
the election”
Tudge’s
comments elicited an article in The Australian on 25 January in response
by the Social Justice Commissioner, Mick Gooda, critical of income management
generally, and the new iteration of income management being advanced by the
Government (‘The welfare card is not the solution to alcohol abuse’). In
particular, Gooda asserts that the welfare card ‘will disproportionately affect
Aboriginal and Torres Strait Islander people, and claw back our hard-won rights
and freedoms’. He also questions the card’s efficacy in reducing alcohol harm,
citing a lack of evidence for such claims. And Gooda begins his op ed by noting
that ‘old wounds are being re-opened. Many of our people are being forced to
revisit the past trauma of income management and stolen wages’.
This latter
point is particularly salient in terms of considering how to proceed with the
new iteration of income management. The implementation of a policy which
engenders strong opposition at a deep emotional level amongst its recipients
will always be highly problematic. Assistant Minister Tudge appears to be
cognisant of these challenges as he has stated he is keen to find a third trial
site in a major regional centre, where around 70 percent of welfare recipients
are non-Indigenous.
How then
should we assess the merits of the policy of income management, and in
particular the Government’s particular approach to taking it forward? Not only
is it complex policy in its own terms, but it has taken on highly symbolic
ideological status, for and against, in both the right and left of the
political spectrum. This accentuates its polarising impact within the ongoing
policy debate on welfare policy, particularly in relation to Indigenous welfare
issues. So for example, those on the left emphasise the alleged infringements
of rights embedded within the policy, whereas conservatives emphasise the
importance of mutual obligation and linking taxpayers contributions to welfare
to societally sanctioned outcomes.
It is worth
contextualising income management policy so as to outline the sequential
development of variant models over the past decade, and to place it in the
longer arc of the history of public policy development.
As mentioned
above, the roots of income management are to be found in the indigenous policy
domain. The current proposals are the fourth iteration of income management to be rolled out over the past decade,
and importantly all three predecessor versions continue to operate. I note in
passing that there are a number of sub-categories to each of the three income
management schemes discussed below.
In Cape
York, the welfare reform agenda funded over the last decade involved a system
where a Family Responsibilities Commission composed largely of community
members has the power to take decisions to effectively income manage welfare
recipients who fail to ensure their children attend school, breach the law, or
fail to meet their tenancy obligations and thus are contributing to social
dysfunction. This system was established at the request of the local
communities and the Cape York Institute, and is virtually entirely Indigenous
in its coverage.
The second
scheme is the so called New Income Management program utilising the NT Basics
Card put in place in 2010 in a revision of the original income management
program introduced as part of the NT intervention in 2007, which quarantines 50
percent of a welfare recipient’s income. This scheme applies to all welfare recipients
across the NT (but not aged or disability pensions), but is almost wholly
Indigenous in its coverage. The original program was protected from legal
challenge by a statutory exclusion of the Racial Discrimination Act, however
the New Income management program has been designed as an explicitly
non-discriminatory scheme.
The third
scheme is Place Based income management which was rolled out by Labor in a
number of locations across Australia, both Indigenous and non-Indigenous.
The three
existing schemes have a limited geographical focus (although the NT scheme
applies across the NT), and are either explicitly or implicitly conceptualised
as trials within the bureaucracy and government.
Turning to
the longer arc of history, income management can be seen to be the product of
previous modes of ‘administering’ Indigenous people’s lives. As is
comprehensively documented in Tim Rowse’s insight-laden history of the origins
of Indigenous citizenship in Central Australia (‘White Flour, White Power’), the entire colonial project in remote Australia was
largely based on the provision of rations to Aboriginal people both through
state sponsored ration depots/settlements and state subsidised pastoral
enterprises.
Rowse
explores the administrative rules which linked the provision of in-kind rations
to Aboriginal people’s readiness and capability to work, the pressures to move
from in-kind rations to more fungible cash payments, and the differing
perceptions of both Aboriginal and settlers regarding the basis for the
respective roles of the parties to the transactions involved.
At a more
abstract level, Rowse argues that rationing policies were embedded in the
policy of assimilation, and that the development of internal contradictions in
the administration of rationing were based in large part on the reluctance of
Aboriginal groups to leave their country to seek employment. Rowse sets out in
detail how these internal contradictions in the administration of rationing
ultimately led to and facilitated the eventual acceptance of remote Aboriginal
community members as citizens, and contributed to the development of the
Whitlam Government’s policy narrative of self-determination as a successor to
paternalism and assimilation.
One of
Rowse’s themes is to recognise the continuities inherent in policy shift from
assimilation to self-determination. For present purposes, it is enough to note
that these continuities continue into the present day and that access to welfare
and the subsequent adoption of income management (albeit in a somewhat
stop/start fashion) is a direct policy descendant of the ration depots of the nineteenth
century. In particular, the internal contradictions remain, as does the
likelihood that Aboriginal and Torres Strait Islander peoples will engage with and
interpret the policy on their own terms and in their own ways.
I focus on
the long road to our present policy position to make the point that policy
development is iterative and the options available are constrained not only by
political imagination and political determination, but also by the largely
invisible yet powerful projection of incremental inertia, which exercises an
extraordinary influence on the imagined parameters of bureaucratic and
political feasibility. In other words, where we are heading is often largely
determined by where we are coming from.
There have
been a number of policy evaluations of income management over the past
five years. While I don’t have the capacity to closely review them here, it is
fair to say that while the conclusions of the more recent evaluations are
positive, the conclusions are far from unequivocal. Moreover, the most comprehensive
and significant review was the evaluation of New Income
Management in the NT
finalised in 2014 by a team of researchers from the Social Policy Research
Centre at UNSW, the Institute of Family Studies and the ANU. This comprehensive
and independent evaluation found that the current New Income Management program
in the NT has not met its objectives. Interestingly, the DSS website (see
hyperlink above) referencing the various evaluations omits to summarise the
results of the NT evaluation.
What does
emerge from a cursory scan of the various evaluations undertaken to date is
that they are highly sensitive to the design parameters and the formal objectives
for each scheme, and that as one might expect, each scheme has its strengths
and weaknesses, and amongst those being income managed, there is a diversity of
views about the utility of the schemes. This suggests that there is a need for
high levels of clarity regarding the policy objectives of income management
schemes if we are to be able to use evaluations as determinative guides to
policy development. Unfortunately, the complexity of the schemes in place, and
the innate amorphousness of the policy and political drivers for the schemes
make this a virtually unattainable aspiration.
My own
assessment of the current policy settings for income management is an amalgam
of the concerns and aspirations of both the left and the right. In an ideal
world, I would support the provision of maximum autonomy for welfare recipients
in the use of their funds. Such a view has the attraction of being
philosophically straightforward, and like the free market theorists who
advocate pure consumer sovereignty, it asserts that no one is better able to
assess an individual’s interests than the individual herself. I also believe
that we have to give serious weight to the multiple considerations canvassed in
the evaluation of the NT scheme. In short, we cannot merely assert or assume
that income management is or will be an unqualified success, and to the extent
that it is pursued as an element of our welfare policy settings, we need to be
prepared to reassess and redesign to ensure that it delivers net benefits.
It is clear
however that income management has established a foothold in our current
welfare policy framework which is based on something more than a broadly
accepted evidence base and a series of technically narrow policy evaluations.
This is reinforced when one notes the comment in the NT evaluation that the
Department of Social Security requested that the evaluation not assess the cost
effectiveness of the program, ostensibly because the requisite data was not available
(page 3, summary report). One of the most salient factors in assessing
Government programs is cost effectiveness; so clearly other forces are at work
here.
Apart from
the fact that the evaluations of income management as implemented so far in
Australia are equivocal at best, and that the program exists for better or for
worse, I consider that there exists a moral imperative for flexible policy
responses in relation to the activities of governments in their engagement with
Indigenous communities, and to a lesser extent, in their engagement with
disadvantaged citizens generally.
In
particular, if Governments are funnelling substantial resources into remote
communities comprised of citizens with poor education, limited financial
literacy, poor health, limited civic governance skills, and with strong
culturally-based social capital, but weak social capital in areas involved in
engagement with the broader society, then in my view government has a
responsibility to understand the implications of those resource flows for the
communities, and if necessary, act to meliorate any adverse consequences. It so
happens that the source of much of those resource flows is the welfare system.
Accordingly I see a rationale for Government intervention, especially in
circumstances where the resources flowing (in this case largely through welfare
payments) are contributing to social dysfunctional and family violence which
impacts vulnerable community members such as he aged, women and children.
This
rationale for Government action is not necessarily an argument for income
management, as there may be other tools to achieve the objective I see as
legitimate. However, income management is one of the potential tools available
to government, and in my view should not be dismissed out of hand.
In
particular, when faced with situations where welfare payments are subsidising
dysfunctional behaviours, often involving violence against women and children,
I can see little justification for maintaining a philosophically pure position
based on the assumption that individuals know best. Moreover, while in many
locations a preponderance of welfare recipients are not engaged in or subject
to dysfunctional activities, I would prefer to see constraints on their access
to fungible resources in order to minimise risks to women and children from the
minority who do engage in dysfunctional behaviour. This point is strengthened
if it is accepted that dysfunctional behaviour is likely to impact beyond the
family and household and have community wide adverse impacts.
Once it is
accepted that there may be a justification for income management of welfare in
some circumstances, the next step is to determine the detailed specification of
those circumstances. This leads on to the detailed design of an effective
income management scheme including the key design parameters which should be in
place. I would add though that the design work should be broadly based, and
extend to the design of the support structures which are an essential adjunct
to successful income management (see below).
Key
challenges facing policy designers are to ensure the scheme assists those most
in need (who are largely those who are most disadvantaged) without adversely
affecting those welfare recipients who don’t require income management; how to
ensure the scheme does not breach the Racial Discrimination Act; how to deal
with welfare recipients who are especially vulnerable and under duress; and how
to minimise the administrative costs of the scheme and keep them within
affordable limits while simultaneously ensuring that individual welfare
recipients’ circumstances are monitored and adjustments made as necessary. These
policy design issues are all substantial challenges for policymakers. Failure
to overcome any one of these challenges engenders the development of the sorts
of internal contradictions which ultimately undermined rationing regimes and
will similarly undermine income management.
Assistant
Minister Tudge deserves significant credit for progressing the next phase of
policy development for income management in a consultative and methodical way,
particularly in relation to its impacts on Indigenous people. The work of the
Forrest Review and aspects of the design report for the Empowered Communities
project, led by experienced Indigenous leaders such as Noel Pearson and Ian
Trust provide a considered and robust foundation for the next steps. Nevertheless,
in my view, there remains a need for further work by the Commonwealth
Government to clarify its policy objectives for income management, and to
establish a transparent and independent process for ensuring that issues which
emerge in the implementation of income management schemes are addressed.
Moreover, there
needs to be recognition that income management can never be an end in itself
and must be seen as a tool to achieve better social outcomes. It will rarely be
able to undertake the heavy lifting required in terms of welfare reform on its
own, and will always require substantial ancillary support services. Indeed,
there is an argument that income management should eventually be seen as the
ancillary support for other more proactive social policy initiatives.
For example,
the NT evaluation noted that one of the reasons why many income managed recipients
in the NT have a positive attitude to income management is that it provides a low
cost and accessible banking service. This suggests that there is a more
fundamental need amongst disadvantaged citizens, particularly in remote
Indigenous communities, for access to improved financial services, for
financial literacy, and for culturally-informed banking services. In the US,
the federal government has a number of schemes in place to incentivise and even
require banks to provide accessible services to disadvantaged citizens, and there
are strong grounds for believing that there is merit in the Australian
Government moving in this direction too.
It follows
that I am broadly supportive of the high level policy directions being pursued
by the Government, and am particularly pleased to see a commitment to a non-discriminatory
policy framework which is a major step forward from the 2007 NT Emergency
Response framework. However there appears to be scope for a much more
adventurous reconceptualisation of the purpose of income management, and for a
much stronger focus on delivering the ancillary support services which will
reinforce the potential positive impact of income management, and potentially
lead to the a new phase where it is no longer required.
Notwithstanding
my support, I do have six critical but I hope constructive comments regarding
the approach being adopted by Assistant Minister Tudge:
·
While
incrementalism is a fact of life in public policy, it seems particularly short
sighted to continually develop new income management schemes while leaving
their predecessor ‘trials’ in place. The result is a chaotic assemblage of
similar yet different income management models, without a coherent policy
rationale articulated by government. Government needs to simplify the number of
different income management designs in operation.
·
It
is time for the Government to move beyond ‘trials’ with limited geographic
focus and develop a universal model, that is , one that potentially applies to
all welfare recipients. The next term of government will see the completion of
a decade since the contentious and poorly implemented initiation of the NT
income management scheme.
·
While
on its face Assistant Minister Tudge’s public statements foreshadow a move to
develop and implement a universal income management scheme, it seems likely
that part of his motivation in spruiking this possibility as a pre-election
policy commitment is to build support and momentum within the Government for
such an outcome. The implementation of a universal nation-wide scheme would
involve considerable costs to the budget (in the hundreds of millions,
potentially even in excess of a billion dollars), and would inevitably be strongly
opposed by Finance and Treasury. The Cabinet endorsed budget rules require all
new expenditure to be offset, yet Assistant Minister Tudge controls no other major
programs from which to source offsets. Either the Prime Minister or the
Minister for Social Security Christian Porter would need to come on board were
a wide ranging expansion of income management to have any prospects of support
within the Cabinet.
·
Alternatively,
a more cynical interpretation of the Assistant Minister’s public statements would
see the spruiking of what is a mere possibility without cabinet endorsement as just
kicking the policy can down the road.
·
The
focus on alcohol by Assistant Minister Tudge raises the question whether the
Government is using the prospect of universal income management at some yet to
be specified time in the future as a means of reducing broader political
pressure to take robust action on the supply of alcohol to remote Indigenous
communities and towns. The policy evidence is clear that a simple measure such
as introducing a volumetric tax on alcohol would make significant inroads on
alcohol abuse. Unfortunately, both the Government and the Opposition, at both
state and federal levels, are in thrall to the substantial electoral funding from the alcohol industry, and
sensible reforms such as this appear not to be on the table.
·
Finally,
while the Government focusses an extraordinary amount of attention on what is
in essence a thin sliver of our welfare system, broader public scrutiny and
debate on the effectiveness and efficacy of our welfare system overall is
curtailed.
Income
management is a crucial social policy issue for Australia. It has particular
resonance in the Indigenous policy domain, and continues to have a polarising
impact notwithstanding the apparent bipartisan support for the policy. There
appears to be a strong bipartisan consensus that any income management policy
ought not to be racially discriminatory and this is driving a focus on
broadening the base beyond discrete Indigenous communities who arguably stand
to benefit most from the successful implementation of a well-designed and
appropriately supported policy.
Nevertheless,
income management raises a tangled web of issues, ranging from different views
on its philosophical foundations, through to more concrete issues such as the
design of effective scheme, determining the appropriate support mechanisms
which are required to complement an effective scheme, and identifying how to
minimise the ongoing duplication of competing models in place, and how to fund
the apparently desired shift to more universal scheme in the face of what
appear to be insurmountable budget constraints.
Charles
Lindblom, an American political scientist was best known for his explanation of
public policy development as ‘muddling through’. Income management of welfare can
potentially contribute to the continued safety and protection of many
disadvantaged citizens, particularly women and children, yet after a decade of ‘muddling
through’, we should not be surprised to find that the current state of play is a
public policy muddle.
The
challenge for Assistant Minister Tudge, and indeed the Government and
Opposition together, is to learn from the models of income management
implemented over the past decade, learn from the evaluations undertaken, and move
beyond the policy foundations established to date to a more flexible, coherent,
non-discriminatory and national policy model for income management. Such a
model would be located within a matrix of complementary government services and
initiatives which operate flexibly to ensure that welfare recipients are
encouraged and incentivised to build the skills and capacities they need to
move beyond welfare.
Ultimately,
we should aim to prioritise and establish much more robust and innovative nationally
implemented policy frameworks for reduced alcohol and substance abuse, for
reduced family violence, for increased financial literacy and improved banking
services which allow our national welfare policy frameworks to move beyond
income management.
This is a
task of policy and strategic imagination, breaking free of the notion that our
pathways forward are constrained by where we have come from. It truly is a
policy objective worthy of our aspirations.
No comments:
Post a Comment